All Bread Is Not Created Equal
Governing authorities in medieval Europe considered only two staples of daily life important enough to regulate: bread and beer. This was done
through assize or assise laws,
which usually came in one of two ways: a separate law of
bread assize and law of beer assize, or a combined law of bread and beer assizes. These laws
dictated the grades of flour purity, based on bran content and mixture
of grains; weight of baked loaves, by measurements of silver currency
(pound, shilling, pence, half- and quarter-penny loaves); and adulteration
of the bread with inedible substances, such as sawdust or hemp. The
prices were set by the state on behalf of the consumer, to prevent
powerful bakers' and brewers' guilds from using their monopolies to
gouge the hungry public. Those who violated the assize laws were subject
to the king's justice, usually in the form of a fine.
As towns formed in the midst of the population boom of the Central
and High Middle Ages, noblemen often wrote bread- and grain-related
laws or stipulations into the founding charters of their cities. The
charter of Winchester, England includes a simplified version of an
assize law, guaranteeing at least a specific weight for white and
dark breads in that town.[1] Other charters sometimes offered generous advantages to townspeople,
as an enticement to emigrate to that growing city. We can see this
in the charters of Lorris, France and Jaca, Spain in the form of free
access to mills or communal ovens, something which, at home on the
countryside manors of noble landlords, was dictated by the landlord
and cost a fee.[2]
Faced with the pressure to get the food on the table quickly, colonial cooks had little time to weigh their ingredients carefully on scales, as had been done in Europe. Scales were time-consuming and costly, so they were abandoned in favor of measuring with cups, glasses and spoons. [3] Though the busiest of colonial and early American women were undoubtedly of the working class, wealthier women also desired more speed and convenience in food preparation. Mary Randolph, a tavern-keeper of the gentry class (a singular occurrence in itself), published a particularly popular cookbook in 1824 entitled The Virginia Housewife. Even her more elegant recipes, when compared to the earlier cookbooks she was referencing, are shortened and simplified and utilize cup- and spoon-measurements, rather than weights.[4]
Later, when the first generations of colonists began to establish
themselves in America, they looked back to their homelands for ideas
of what kinds of laws were necessary to establish a peaceful, orderly
society. In some colonies, such as Georgia, they adopted the medieval
tradition of assize laws, since bread was still a significant part
of the daily diet. Compared side by side, the similarities between
the English Bread Assizes from the Reigns of Henry II to Edward II
and the Act for Regulating the Assize of Bread from the Legislature
of Georgia are striking. For example, the Georgian Assize says the
following:
no person or persons whatsoever shall make for
sale, or sell, or expose to sale, within this province, any sort
or sorts of soft bread made of wheat, other than the several sorts
herein after-mentioned, viz. White, wheaten, and household
bread; all which several sorts of soft bread shall be made in their
several and respective degrees, according to the goodness and fineness
of the several sorts of flour of which the same ought to be made
and when fine wheat flour is ordinarily sold for money in Savannah,
at any of the rates herein after-mentioned, the assize and weight
of the said white, wheaten, and household bread, respectively, are
and shall be set and ascertained according to the following tables
in avoirdupois weight, and so proportionably when fine flour shall
be ordinarily sold in Savannah for more or less money than is specified
in the said tables, wherein the white loaves shall always be one
half, and the wheaten three quarters, of the weight of household
loaves.[3]
In comparison, the English law likewise lays out three classes of
bread: Wastel, Simnel, and Cocket, from highest to lowest in quality,
with the lowest quality expected to weigh the most, because of highest
bran content. A fourth kind, a bread of Treet, or dessert bread, is
also mentioned, but would have been a more irregular purchase, not
a menu staple like the other three. The English law also specifies
the grades of flour that would be used in each kind of bread, as does
the Georgian law.[4]
A few interesting differences present themselves in the Georgian
assize law, however, mainly in the form of enforcement and punishment.
Georgian bakers are required to make an identification mark on their
bread, so its origin is apparent, and their bakeries, shops, warehouses,
even their homes, are required to be open for inspection by the justices
of the peace at any time, night or day! Refusing or hindering these
searches could cost a baker a fine of five pounds sterling, to be
given to the local poor charities — no matter whether or not he were
actually hiding any crime or wrongdoing!
If any bread is found to be in violation of the law, not only is
the baker to be brought up on charges which could lead to a fine of
up to twenty shillings, but all the baker's bread is also confiscated by
the justices and distributed to the local poor charities. This punishment
could be incurred by bakers guilty of just not putting their stamp
on a batch of loaves — they might not have done a single thing wrong
with the bread itself! One stopgap measure did exist on behalf of
the bakers, though. The justices had only three days to prosecute
a case from the time when the offending loaf was found. After that
time, the complaint was invalid, and the justices would have to watch
and wait for the next infraction.
However, if certain features of this law sound to you as if they
were at odds with the ideals of the fledgling colonies — little things
like life, liberty, the pursuit of happiness and a fair dollar —
you're not the only one. To many colonial bakers trying to operate
in the new environment of a free market economy, the assize laws were not
balancing the scales anymore, they were putting the heavy hand of
government on them. In the Petition for the Repeal of the Act to
Regulate the price and assize of bread, a coalition of
Massachusetts bakers tell us in their own words why Old World assize
laws don't work in the New World economy:
"In Great Britain, the Bakers are and have
been, for more than 400 years, an incorporated company, possessing
exclusive privileges; and authorized to restrain, by limitations
and restrictions of various sorts, the competition to a smaller
number, than might otherwise go into this business — which is attended
with the same consequences, as a monopoly, though in a less degree.
To counterbalance the evils of these incorporations, this law, was
produced... — In Massachusetts there is no incorporation of Bakers
— they enjoy no exclusive privileges — they possess no authority
to refrain or limit their number — or to combine, in any manner,
for the purpose of raising the price of their labour, or the profits
of their stock — The only apology, then, for such a law in England,
happily for its citizens, does not exist in America."[5]
The bakers in this text complain that not only is the law un-American
— "unjust and oppressive on a part of the community, and inconsistent
with the principles of our free Constitution" — but also other
factors in the colonies, in addition to the assize laws, work against
the bakers. At the time when the law was first instituted, they complain,
grain had been imported unmanufactured, so bakers could keep and profit
from the sale of the separated bran product. Now, though, processed
flour is imported by itself, and the bakers are taking the loss. Even
the weather in America conspires against them, the bakers say! Doughy
loaves in summer months are guilty of a multitude of sins: they often
spread out and obscure the required ID markings, or stick together
so that the precise measurements of each loaf are altered.
The importation of communal ovens to colonial villages from Europe,
such as those from Devon in the 17th century, and the sale
by street-hawkers of "bread-water," probably yeast water
or a sourdough starter of some kind in medieval cities, suggests that
perhaps lower urban classes and colonial families still baked some
bread products for themselves.[6] But the Massachusetts baker John White probably frames the situation
best when he says that "every family however large or small,
or wherever living, may bake their own bread — and certainly will,
unless they can purchase for less money, than they can buy the
Grain and bake it in their own families." [italics
mine]. The transition from home baking to commercial baking was doubtless
one of convenience and economy. In medieval Europe, where bakers'
guilds formed powerful professional monopolies, the assize laws were
the customers' guarantee of a low price and a consistent product.
In the new world colonies, although the laws were brought over like
a piece of heirloom furniture, both producers and consumers quickly
discovered that it just did not fit the new environment —
the free market in a new society did the job of the old assizes.
Appendices
The Bread Assizes mentioned in this text are available here as full text handouts to students.
Notes
Return to:
In-Depth Articles
|
|
|